Industrial democracy is one of the issues left over from the recent Contract negotiations between the International Woodworkers of America and the lumber bosses. _ The February wage and contract Conference set the stage when it adopted the following resolution: “That we demand the setting up of a joint management-union com- mittee mutually agreed upon for the purpose of drafting recom- mendations for sharing decision- making.’’ I spoke recently with a number of active IWA members. They said they expected very little from the talks that will take place between the union and management on this 'Ssue. In the first place, a two-year Contract has been signed and management is therefore under no _ pressure to make substantial _ Concessions. But union leaders have never revealed their precise Proposals nor has the membership been involved as yet in discussing the extension of workers’ rights. The report on co-determination delivered to the wage and contract Conference was. critical of the Concept, which involves electing Workers to boards of directors as token members, with the ultimate authority on the most vital issues remaining in the hands of the -€mployers. Nevertheless a resolution in favor of “sharing decision-making” was adopted. It Should be noted in this context that the report called for widening the Scope of collective bargaining. It Proposed that such questions as job enrichment, job rotation and a workers’ voice in decisions af- fecting production should be in- cluded in the collective agreement. Industrial.democracy debate opens It is not likely that the owners of: the largestindustry in the province will surrender any of their major prerogatives just because IWA leaders engage them in a friendly discussion. If it was otherwise, it would be a different world for woodworkers, a world with no classes and no class struggle. Those officers, job stewards and activemembers who are genuinely concerned with extending the scope of collective bargaining will no doubt begin to speak up. As a. start, they might consider asking the Regional Negotiating Com- mittee to spell out what they will be asking for in talks with management. If there is to be any LABOR COMMENT BY JACK PHILLIPS workers in managing the industry, it should start with meaningful participation in formulating union policy. For some thirty years now, the debate on extending industrial democracy has been confined to narrow circles. As a matter of fact, it has been discussed more widely in certain academic and political circles than in the trade union movement itself. Despite the ob- vious weaknesses of the concept of tripartism as advanced by the Canadian Labor Congress, it played a positive role in drawing attention to the limitations of collective bargaining as we know it today. The terms industrial democatcy and workers’ control are used frequently by those who theorize on the role of the trade unions. In- dustrial democracy is sometimes referred to the first stage -in workers’ control which, in turn, is defined as direct control over the scheduling of work, the speed of production, work methods and the selection of supervision. Workers’ control is also spoken of as the power to have a veto over layoffs, discipline and other management rights. Most advocates of workers’ control argue that at some point the workers must take up the question of public ownership of the decisive sectors of the economy, to consolidate the gains made through separate industrial ac- tions. and to create the conditions for overall economic planning. To. achieve those ggals and to protect the workers from a state controlled by the owning class, they advocate combining economic action with political action. Political action would make it possible to win allies outside the labor movement in the ' long, dawn-out struggle against the meaningful participation by the. monopolies. It would also open the way to a government that would use state power to accelerate the process of taking power from the monopolies, thus advancing the working people to a dominant position in society. Those who argue in favor of extending industrial democracy include Communists, members of the NDP And some who lean in the direction of syndicalism. Those who have the syndicalist approach tend to over-emphasize industrial action in relation to political ac- tivity and to blindly worship the spontaneous flare-up. They play down the role of political ideology and fail to understand the ~ catalyzing role of a mass ’ revolutionary party with its main base in the working class and the trade union movement. The Communist Party of Canada has given a constructive lead on the extension of collective bargaining. In his concluding remarks to the recent convention of the party, William Kashtan, ee ~~] WA DELEGATES IN CONVENTION... the convention touched on industrial democracy but has yet to determine where it is going on the issue. party leader, pledged the full support of his party to the concept that workers should have a say on all questions of concern to the working class. “This is a basic democratic issue” he said, ‘‘which hits at monopoly power. The more one hits on the question of why the working class has no rights on questions that are of concern to them, the more one poses the limitations of bourgeois democracy and the fact that on basic questions the workers have no rights to all. Those rights are the sole prerogative of management. The battle on this issue becomes animportant part of the struggle against monopoly and for fundamental change at this time.”’ “At the same time we must warn against ‘the right of a say’ being perverted and distorted to forms of class collaboration, which the right wing in the NDP and the trade union movement not given up. Britain is a classical example, as is West Germany.” Marketing boards investigation into the high cost of This is the second of two artricles Summarizing the submission of the Vancouver and District Labor Council to the provincial govern- ment’s select standing committee on agriculture and food costs. Prepared by the Trade Union Research Bureau the brief has two main sections: production and marketing; and processing and retailing. Last week the Tribune looked at the processing and retailing section of the food in- dustry and found corporate con- centration in this portion of the food industry to be the principal Cause of high food costs. This week, We drawon the Labor Council brief to explain the controversy Surrounding marketing boards, which has been singled out by the Media and the provincial govern- ment’s committee as the scapegoat for high food costs. * *e * Marketing boards. You could Substitute almost any dirty word ' Without changing the subject in the Current discussion on high food Costs. Add ‘‘egg” marketing board, or “boiler chicken” marketing board, or “milk”? marketing board and the curses will really fly. Food Costs have jumped by over six Percent in the first six months of this year in B.C. and without a doubt, the marketing boards are the most frequently named as the Villians. But are the charges just? Are Marketing boards the principal Cause of high food costs, and, more to the point, would foot costs come down if marketing boards were dismantled? _ A look at the facts shows that an food will reveal few answers if the Marketing board critics, for the main focus of the inquiry. Makreting board critics, for example, have made a lot of noise about the fact that chicken prices are substantially higher in B.C. than in Ontario. A closer look, though, finds that 89 percent of the higher price accrues to wholesalers and retailers, and not to the producers through the marketing boards. That is not to say that marketing boards are beyond criticism. They are certainly part of the in- stitutionalized system of corporate rip offs that cause high food costs. But they should be weighted up factually, in the context of that system. : There are over 100 marketing boards in Canada that handle about 60 percent of farm produce in the country. All marketing boards are under provincial jurisdictions, except for wheat and fish. For eggs and turkeys there is a federal umbrella agency that groups together the provincial boards. In B.C. thereare 11 marketing boards covering vegetables, tree fruits, broiler chickens, _ oysters, mushrooms, eggs, turkeys, cranberries, grapes and milk. The concept of a marketing board was pioneered and fought for long and hard by western family farmers. during the 1920’s and 1930’s. They demanded an orderly marketing system to stop the price manipulation of commodity speculators and big business corporate buyers and processors. ‘One of the first breakthroughs aren't th came in B.C. When a strike of fruit and vegetable growers in the early 1930’s won the Natural Products Marketing Act of 1934. The marketing board stablizied farm income and stopped _in- dependent farmers from _ being completely wiped out. During the 1960’s a second group of marketing boards came into being. This time, however, it was e real vil themselves are often dominated by corporate extensions of the agribusiness giants that rule the processing and retailing sections of the industry as well. Farmer’s organizations like the National Farmers Union have long demanded collective bargaining rights for farmers as the only way to ensure that the producer gets a fair shake, and to ensure that the What would happen if marketing hoards were done away with? Harbor no illusions that the free market would provide lower food costs. the modern inflationary spiral that provided the motive. In the 1930’s boards set minimum prices; in the 1960’s prices were set according to cost of production. The marketing boards were established to get the farmer more income. It is fairly clear then, that the boards have made for generally higher retail prices in food. But having said that, the real problem with marketing boards is © their lack of market power. In the first place, the food market is a national market and most boards are provincial; and hence, in competition with each other. The giant corporate buyers — four retail chains monopolize Canada’s food industry — exercise far greater market power than the boards. Secondly, the marketing boards marketing boards operate in the interests of the majority of far- mers. But what would happen if the boards were done away with, as some people suggest? Harbor no illusions that the “free market’? would provide food at lower prices. An example is the beef industry, which in the absence of any marketing authorities (although the legislation for it is said to be in the works) has a so-called “free market.” Four years ago beef prices were soaring 30 percent per year; two anda half years ago beef prices were climbing 20 percent per year; one and a half years ago prices were rising 15 percent per year and it’s still increasing by around 10 percent at present. While the price to the consumer went sky high, thousands of small cattle producers during these years went PACIFIC TRIBUNE—OCTOBER 14, 1977—Page 3 ains bankrupt as the industry became increasingly concentrated. Ob- viously an open market for farm produce is a chaotic luxury that we can least afford. The fact is that the agribusiness giants will benefit with or without the marketing boards through the process of vertical integration, or the takeover of related producers by big capitalist farmers. The real danger is of the power over prices and supply that the corporate sector will wield if corporate producers completely take over and dominate the marketing boards as they do the processing and retailing sections of the in- dustry. Marketing boards should not be abolished, but they should be transformed into institutions that protect both producer and con- sumer. All marketing authorities should be run by a governing council with equal representattion from producers, consumers and labor. They should be publicly accountable for their actions and issue quarterly reports on major decisions that, in turn, should be open for appeal. That kind of marketing authority, while not equipped to deal with the principal cause of high food costs — the retail food monopolies — could go a long way in bringing about some changes in agriculture that would increase food production and raise farm income, without raising consumer prices. Now about those retail - food monopolies, Mr. minister. . .