ia caine spore nme erase B.C. Fed march in support of J. P. Stevens workers, Nov- ember, 1978. ‘Historic’ victory at JP Stevens Workers at the J.P. Stevens textile company in Southern U.S. have won a historic victory with an agreement from the company to recognize the Amalgamated Clothing and Textile Workers Union. The victory caps a decade | long struggle to win union recognition from the textile company, known throughout the labor movement for its anti- union and union busting ac- tivities. Throughout the ten year struggle, ACTWU received strong soldarity from the labor movement throughout North America, including a continent- wide boycott of J.P. Stevens textile products. The agreement with J.P. Stevens was won by the 3,000 workers at the company’s Roanoke Rapids, North Carolina plant, but it includes provisions to extend the result of collective bargaining at that plant to any other J.P. Stevens plant where ACTWU wins a cerification vote. a In an attempt to split an smash the union in its Roanoke Rapids plant stronghold, the textile company had granted wage increases to workers in other plants of eight and one- half percent in 1978 and 1979 and 10 percent this year. The workers at Roanoke Rapids were offered the same contract providing they signed an agree- ment which would have exclud- ed ACTWU. Workers at the North Carolina plant stuck with ACT- WU, however, even though it meant a loss of $40 per week for two year, for workers earning only $4.50 per hour. The agreement includes recognition of the union at Roanoke Rapids and in several other plants in Alabama and elsewhere. If government in Canada ac- cepted the advice of Sandra Christ- ensen, an assistant professor of economics at Simon Fraser. Univer- sity in Burnaby, public employees who now enjoy the right to strike would lose that right. That is the message of her 1980 book entitled Unions And The Public Interest. The book was published by the Fraser Institute of Vancouver, a privately funded organization which describes itself as ‘“‘an inde- pendent Canadian economic and social research and educational or- ganization.” The guideline the institute uses in its approach to collective bargain- ing for public employees is contain- ed in this formulation: ‘““Where competitive markets have been re- placed by government control, the interest of the Institute lies in docu- menting objectively the nature of the improvement or deterioration resulting from government inter- vention.” That is the guideline used by Christensen in her book. There- fore, neither the Institute nor the professor can truly lay claim to documenting the problems of col- lective bargaining in the public sec- tor from a neutral viewpoint. Their starting point is that what is good for the competitive market system (including layoffs and unemploy- ment) is good for all of society. Thus, they fall in line with those who say that what is good for the big monopolies and the multina- tional corporations which domin- ate our economy, is also good for working people. Inher conclusions, she places the problem as she sees it: ‘‘. . large gains by public sector employees may have undesirable conse- quences in the private sector, in the form of unemployment and labor unrest. These can occur because private sector employees may resist accepting wages lower than the wages paid comparable employees in the public sector. Hence, private sector unions may become more militant in their wage demands, in an attempt to catch up to the public sector. Because private sector em- -ployers do face profit constraints, they may be unable to grant wage increases as large as those obtained by public sector workers, and num- erous work stoppages may result.”” After creating this hypothetical danger to the economy of our country (higher wages for public employees than those of private sector employees), the professor goes on to advance the following recommendation: “We would advance that bar- gaining over pay be eliminated in the public sector. We would advo- cate a system of limited collective bargaining in which overall com- pensation levels are not negotiable, although the division between pay and fringe benefits might be a le- gitimate topic for bargaining. The overall level of compensation for each job type would be determined in each jurisdiction by an inde- pendent and continuing wage board, whose decisions would be based on strict private sector com- parability guidelines. Both em- Jack Phillips ployer and employee groups would be welcometo make submissions to the wage board, but bargaining as such would not take place. Since the level of compensation would not be subject to collective bargain- ing, naturally, strikes to win in- creased compensation would be prohibitied.”’ It is interesting to note how Christensen expresses her doubts at another point: ‘‘Public employees have demonstrated that they are willing to strike, illegally if neces- sary, when they are convinced that they are not being treated fairly. Even without a strike, employee discontent can take the form of more subtle job actions or (inac- tion) which can be just as disruptive as a strike. While the substitution of binding arbitration for the strike as the means by which bargaining impasses are resolved in the public sector is currently a popular idea, those experienced with it are nega- tive to the idea.”’ However, after dismissing com- pulsory arbitration as a method for resolving labor-management dis- putes in the public service, the pro- fessor appears to contradict herself by proposing a more sophisticated form of compulsory arbitration: a wage board that would have the au- thority to set wages. “The wage board we propose is very similar to the Industrial Peace Commission suggested by Leland Hazard of the Carnegie Institute of Technology ... In order to free the commis- sion or board from political influ- ence, Hazard suggests that its members, who would be drawn from labor, industry, the profes- sions and the universities, be ap- pointed on a long-term basis such as Supreme Court judges are.”’ What we have hereis yet another version of the so-called, impartial labor court, this time to bemadeup largely of people trained in eco- nomics rather than in law. No responsible and knowledge- able leader of any public service un- ion in Canada, whether at the mu- nicipal, provincial or federal level, would agree it is possible to set up such a wage board'that would be truly impartial and fully insulated from the political pressures of the government of the day and im- mune to the influence of the big business establishment. Life being what it is, such boards would, in each case, be set up by the very gov- ernments (or agencies responsible to them) which the unions have had to fight, to the point of going on strike. As to appointments from the universities, the unions would be more likely than not to be con- fronted with types like professor Sandra Christensen, who in her book deplores the fact that the ma- jority of public employees in Can- ada enjoy the right to strike, which is not the case, as she points out, in the United States where she was ed- ucated, or in Great Britain. Fur- ther, any labor leaders appointed to such a board say, by the Trudeau government, would be conserva- tive labor leaders who would at best serve as a screen for the dominant majority. The threat to the trade union movement contained in the Christ- ensen thesis is illustrated by the fol- lowing proposals she advances in connection with the possibility of strikes in the public service: @ Public employers should in- sist on limiting union security clauses to the Rand Formula, under which all employees in the bargaining unit would be required to pay a ‘‘bargaining fee’’ to the union, but would not be required to become union members. In that case, those non-union members who did not support the strike could continue to report for work without fear of fines or loss em- ployment arising from union im- posed sanctions. @ The effectiveness of. strikes should be reduced by automating the employees’ most critical func- tions or by contracting out at least a portion of them. @ Citizens should be given the right to sue government and the un- ion for normal services not provid- ed during a strike. @ When compensation of pub- lic employees become ‘‘too expens- ive,”’ public employment should be cut by layoffs, attrition, automa- tion and contracting out to the pri- vate sector. She also suggests that there should be more extensive use of the lockout by public employers and more widespread use of scabs to re- place strikers. Completely missing from the book is the fact, for example, that in British Columbia all the big em- ployer bargaining agencies, in bo the private and public sectors, CO- ordinate their bargaining strategies through the Employers’ Council of British Columbia. The Council is always pressing governments to put the lid on compensation for public employees in order to be ina better position to hold down private sec- tor wage costs, and because they know that if the public sector can be saddled with what amounts to wage controls, it will be easier tO apply the same controls to workers in the private sector. This design must be seen against a backdrop of prices and taxes rising faster than wages, in the overall picture, thus producing more profits for the monopoly and multinational cor- porations. Another case the professor fail- ed to cite is Alberta, where the pro- — vincial government instituted vol- untary wage guidelines after the federal government abandoned its wage control program. The Al- berta government tries to impose those guidelines on public employ- ees and urges private industry to follow. First set up to keep wage in- creases to between six and 7.5 per- cent a year, this year the guidelines have been moved up toa 7.5 tonine percent range, with inflation run- ning at almost 10 percent. Alberta provincial government employees. it should be noted, do not enjoy the right to strike. Like the other.economists who have produced studies for the Fra- ser Institute she is definitely in the conservative camp. I do not believe that her book will convince many trade union members. However, it was not written for that purpose. It was designed as part of the big busi- ness war of ideas to discredit the trade union movement in the minds of millions of Canadians and thus facilitate the passage of more re- strictive labor legislation. I am hopeful that the union movement will use all the resources at its dis- posal to counteract such mislead- ing propaganda. ‘Not’ not meant The word ‘‘not’’ found its way into the wrong place in Labor Comment last week, leaving the opposite impression from that _ which was intended. The sentence — incorrectly — said “‘It is re- ported that the AFL-CIO fraternal delegates . told president George Meany that the left had taken control of the CLC, which was not far from being the case.”’ It should, of course, have read «< . .which was far from being the: case.” Ontario | jobs rally hits plant closures Continued from page 1 all the speakers at the rally was the same: Ontario working peo- ple will not tolerate the pro- vince’s deindustrialization and the thousands of jobs that are being taken away. Cliff Plikey, president of the 800,000 member Ontario Federation of Labor, rejected ‘Ontario labor minister Robert Elgie’s do-nothing proposals on plant closures announced in the legislature Oct. 14. Pilkey said Elgie’s statement failed to meet the OFL’s main demands: public justification of closures by runaway corpora- tions; one week leave serverance pay for every year of service; complete pension portability; and, increased notice of a com- pany’s intention to shut down or lay off workers to at least six months. The OFL president warned the Tory government that work- ing people want it to make full employment its number one priority. The rally’s purpose, Pilkey said, was to tell Davisand the Tories, ‘‘either you change or we'll change your govern- ment.”” Bob White, United Auto Workers Canadian director called for the Ontario govern- ment to seizé the assets of cor- porations that are shutting down until all the workers’ claims on the runaway com- panies have been settled to the workers’ satisfaction. Referring to the OFL’s se- cond phase in the ‘‘Ontario can work”? campaign - which is a collection of more than two million protest cards to be sign- ed and presented to the premier, White said to the rally ‘“‘Go home and finish the job. Tell Bill Davis we need legislation on plant closures and if you don’t do it, then step aside and we’ll put somebody in who will do the job.” Ontario Public Services Employees’ union president Sean O’Flynn declared “‘it’s time we had a government that stopped presiding over the disintegration of Ontario’s in- dustrial base.”? Dick Barry, United Electrical president said the root cause of the shutdown epidemic was the branch plant nature of Ontario’s economy. ‘Decisions affecting the lives: of thousands of Canadian workers,” he said, ‘‘are being made in U.S. corporate boar- drooms. “It’s time we told them enough is enough,” Barry said. PACIFIC TRIBUNE—OCT. 24, 1980—Page 12