i ‘\ { a: ai i ’ 2 Tt — A _ ‘a H: 1 (i a tI, ay baer eilbarieetarrmr arin mit % i er er ec a ie en a heey ae, nowy Eee Midas Raw This week — Pulp: revenue arrow misses the target n Oct. 1, 1987, the government of British Columbia changed a few things that would have an impact on the forest industry. Were these changes for the better or worse? Some said it was for the better. The new policy would remove a 15 percent export tax on softwood lumber, it meant predictable revenues for the for the provincial government, and it meant that the larger forest companies would become directly responsible for replanting where they harvested. But many didn’t believe this new policy was an improvement over the old system. Some even said it would destroy the industry. Who was right? As far as thé stumpage appraisal system is concerned, the change was basic. The old Rothery system began with an assumed selling price of the end product. This was divided by a "profit and risk allow- ance" which allowed the company a 13 percent profit plus additional risk allowances for fluctuating prices, decadent timber and excep- tional road construction and log- ging costs. From this the total operating costs were subtracted; those cost were basically, the predicted cost of harvesting the trees, hauling them to the mill, and producing the lumber. The new system, the Compara- tive Value Timber Pricing system, offered a new concept in business management. The first considera- tion was to be a "target rate". This "target rate" would be the total amount collected by the province through stumpage rates in any given year. . Once the government decided - how much they needed or wanted, all companies would be assessed a stumpage trate either above or below an average that was based on timber quality and ease of logging. These "target" averages were set at $10.59 per cubic metre on the coast and $8.59 per cubic meter in the interior. The direct "profit and risk allow- ance", though, was gone. It was a thing of the past. Particularly the profit side ‘of things. Profit was something that forest companies could only hope they would eam, but it wouldn’t happen unless world market lumber prices just happened to be higher than their costs. If they weren’t, forest com- panies would just have to settle for a loss. And there were other changes that some felt might compound the risk of losing money rather than earning it. That is, for the forest company. The government’s profit, remember, was - predetermined before any of the other factors were known. tet A ne of these changes was QO the time allowed between setting new averages. The old -system was based on an average of actual market prices for the previous three months. This meant that if prices dropped, forest companies would have to sell their lumber products at a lower profit, or perhaps even a loss, for any- where up to three months. On the plus side of things, though, when market prices rose those same companies could expect compara- tive windfall profits for the next three months. The new system, however, changed this time frame to six months. This meant that if prices dropped, forest companies would have to operate with low profits or a loss for a much longer period of time, and some believed that period of time might be too long for any company that was in any- thing but excellent financial health. Adding to the problem was the simple fact of life that market | — Letter to the Editor — _ - Still no clear answer to Sustut question To the Editor; During the Premier’s recent town hall meeting in Terrace the issue of timber from the Sustut- Takla came up. Someone wanted to know why timber which should have gone to Hazelton and Smithers was given instead to Prince George. The questioner was concerned because that action had resulted in the closure of a Hazelton mill and it had also been a severe economic blow to Smithers, The person who should have been made to answer that question — former Minister of Forests at the time — Dave Parker, ever said a word. Not surprising since Dave once admitted on radio that he hadn’t been in as much trouble now that he was saying less. In- stead it was the Premier and the present Minister of Forests who dealt with the issue. The Premier responded by claiming that not to give the wood to the Prince George firms would have cost Prince George a hundred jobs. Before anyone could remind him that it cost Hazelton and Smithers more than that, he turned the question over the Claude Richmond. Mr. Richmond explained that the issue had been discussed by Catinet ‘‘a number of times’’ and that the decision had been ‘avery difficult one’’ for Cabinet. His new estimate for job losses to Prince George if it did not get the timber stood at g Pifer “== Continued from page A6 terms under which the Vander © Zalms operated the theme park for the past four years. Meanwhile, the media con- tinues to do what it has always done — and that is to reflect what is truly happening, rather than to present only the ‘government's, or Mr. Vander Zalm’s, interpretation of it. Premier - Vander Zalm has more than once accused me and other commentators on the B.C. political scene of being negative, negative, negative. As a rabid optimist who always sees the glass as half full, rather than half empty, I disagree. Here are a couple of thoughts to bolster my argu- ment. 1. I am positive that he believes that the Fantasy Gardens scandal is a ‘‘side issue’”’ of little relevance or im- portance in the whole scheme of things, and is not even a scandal. 2. I am positive that he is dead wrong on that, and it may well cost him his government or his position, or both. How’s that for being positive?! 300 to 400. No comment was made about the equal if not more severe impact of a loss of employment to towns the size of Hazelton or Smithers, There was nary a peep from Mr. Parker and he is still the official rep- resentative of the Hazeltons and Smithers. While listening to all the talk about Cabinet dealing with the issue, I was reminded of the ex- change which is recorded in Hansard and which took place in the Legislature on June 20, 1988. The Sustut-Takla decision had just been announced. NDP member Bob Williams asked the then-Minister of Forests, Dave Parker: ‘“‘With respect to the Takla matter, the chief forester made that decision. Is that the case?’’ Parker answers, ‘‘The deputy chief forester made that decision, The chief forester was not available,” How could anyone who took part in ‘ta number of Cabinet discussions’ on the matter when it was a very ‘“‘difficult decision’ (for Cabinet) not know the dif- ference between ‘the deputy chief forester making that deci- sion’, and ‘Cabinet making the decision’? The fact that Cabinet did not have the legal right to grant forest licenses in June of 1988 may have had something to do with Parker’s inability to give a clear answer, Helmut Giesbrecht, "New Democratic Candidate for Skeena. | < by Tod Strachan, in consultation with Rod Arnold and Doug Davies Terrace Review — Wednesday, October 17, 1990 Al Forestry prices always drop much faster than they rise. The recovery time under this new system, then, might be much longer than the industry could stand. There was something else to be considered from the industry’s point of view. Costs rose with the introduction of the Comparative value system by about 15 percent. Why? In the mid-1980’s the United States decided Canadian lumber was unfair competition in the U.S. market. Our forest indus- try, they said, was subsidized through low stumpage rates. So to bring things into better balance, they slapped on a 15 percent import tariff. . The Canadian federal government had a solution to this dilemma, however. They told the U.S. that if they dropped their import tariff, Canada would apply a 15 percent export tax to all softwood lumber headed for the American market. The Americans agreed and at least this. way, reasoned Ottawa, the 15. percent stayed in Canada. Some though, called it a band-aid solu- tion. Victoria didn’t like the idea at all. A tax revenue from their ‘resource going into federal coffers wasn’t a good plan at all. So, a new solution: build the 15 percent into the province’s stumpage ap- pmaisal formula and perhaps Ottawa might drop the export tax. And it worked. Now, they said, at least all that money is staying in the province. S parative Pricing system there was at least one player who was assured an income. The government, with their "target rate", always knew exactly how much they would earn. In fairness, it could be argued that if the pro- vince planned to put all this forestry-generated revenue back into the forest industry, reforesta- tion and stand tending might be a good place to invest it, the plan was a good one. It was financially sound. Unfortunately, however, re- investment in the industry didn’t seem to be a part of the govern- ment’s plan. Revenue from stump- age fees still goes directly into gencral revenue and is spent on things like new roads and hos- pitals; only a very small part of It is ever spent on insuring the future of that revenue. A revenue, that if it’s not protected, could dry up. Some observers, therefore, don’t view this system as a very sound long-term plan. Of course, the old system wasn’t perfect either and many of those who oppose the new system might o under this new Com- ee have been brought on-side if some of the Rothery system short- comings had been addressed, One opportunity missed, for example, was the opportunity to make the pulp industry begin to paying their own way in the world and take that burden off the lumber indus- try. But it didn’t, and many see this as a flaw that could endanger the financial viability of the lum- ber industry. Sawmills sell chips to the pulp industry at a loss and are expected to recover their loss through profits on their lumber... profits that all too often aren’t even there. For the pulp industry, though, who have to compete on world markets, the system offers a suitable supply of low-cost base product allowing them to operate at a profit. Obviously, some people can appreciate the benefits of such a system. Particularly, for example, the board of directors who manage a pulp mill. Unfortunately, how- ever, « this. same’ system’ which seems to offer them such great benefits has led the powers-that-be to make a wrong decision. A good example of this was seen in the recession of the carly 1980’s. A number of boards of directors looked at the balance sheet and discovered that their sawmill was losing money while their pulp mill was making it. They forgot about the "subsidy" on chips, therefore, and decided to re-invest profits into their pulp mills. Perhaps they could even increase their output and make even more money. The result, though, was predict- able. Upgraded pulp mills needed more chips, and that meant their sawmills made even less monty than they did before. Today, those sawmills are inefficient, out of date, but they don’t generate enough profit to warrant an upgrade. Another downside to this story is the fact that it means tuming even more trees into chips, and that might mean poor utili- zation of our remaining resource. This could be viewed as the beginning of a downward spiral for the lumber industry, and in the end, selling off our last tree for far less than it’s worth. And when that happens, there will be nothing to debate. B happen. Perhaps one day the U.S. will decide that selling chips to the our pulp indus- try below market value is in fact subsidizing that industry. And if they do, they might introduce a 15 percent import tariff on our pulp. ut perhaps that won't — Continued on page AB